Skip to main content
Log in

A nonlinear state marginal price vector model for the task of business valuation. A case study: The dimensioning of IT-service companies under nonlinear synergy effects

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Central European Journal of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the present contribution we present a nonlinear extension of the innovative linear investment-oriented company valuation method and so-called state marginal price vector model of Toll which represents a two-step procedure separated into a base and a valuation approach. As novel aspect we address nonlinear synergy effects in M&A’s. For this purpose we introduce a nonlinear framework within a semi-discrete convex optimization approach. As capital market assumption we simulate an imperfect market. To demonstrate the usefulness of the method, we address a case study of a merger of two IT-service companies. The related valuation and dimensioning of capacities is done by solving a multi-period newsvendor model under stochastic demand. The demonstrated nonlinear framework is shown to be suitable for a wide range of business valuation tasks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To bridge the gap between linear and nonlinear programming, we can analyze Eq. (26) and observe that \(h(Q) = P(Q) - Q \, \partial _Q P(Q)\). Hence, considering an unbounded and linear and, thus, homogeneous function of degree \(k=1\) we can conclude that the related object is marginal or unrealized using the Euler relation \(Q \, \partial _Q P = k \, P(Q)\) for a homogeneous function \(P(\lambda \, Q) = \lambda ^k \, P(Q)\) of degree k since \(h(Q) = (1-k) \, P(Q) = 0\), which is indeed zero.

References

  • Albach H (1962) Investition und Liquidität. Gabler, Wiesbaden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alfares HK, Elmorra HH (2005) The distribution-free newsboy problem: Extensions to the shortage penalty case. Int J Prod Econ 93–94(1):465–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allais M (1953) Le Comportement de l’Homme Rationnel devant le Risque: Critique des Postulats et Axiomes de l’Ecole Americaine. Econometrica 21(4):503–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelus A, Porteus EL (2002) Simultaneous capacity and production management of short-life-cycle, produce-to-stock goods under stochastic demand. Manage Sci 48(3):399–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1964) The role of securities in the optimal allocation of risk-bearing. Rev Econ Stud 31(2):91–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertsekas DP (1999) Nonlinear programming, 2nd edn. Athena Scientific, Belmont

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronstein IN, Semendjajew KA (1991) Convex optimization. In: Handbook of mathematics (German edition, Ergänzende Kapitel), 6th edn. Harri Deutsch, Frankfurt, pp 135–137

  • Brösel G, Matschke MJ, Olbrich M (2012a) Valuation of entrepreneurial businesses. Int J Entrep Ventur 4(3):239–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brösel G, Toll M, Zimmermann M (2011) What the financial crisis reveals about business valuation. Manag Econom 5(10):27–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Brösel G, Toll M, Zimmermann M (2012b) Lessons learned from the financial crisis unveiling alternative approaches within valuation and accounting theory. Financ Rep 4(4):87–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Casimir RJ (2002) The value of information in the multi-item newsboy problem. Omega 30(1):45–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman L (2014) Why finance theory fails to survive contact with the real world: A fund manager perspective. Crit Perspect Account 25(3):226–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland JE, Koller T, Murrin J (1990) Valuation. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Damodaran A (2011) Applied corporate finance, 3rd edn. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G (1959) Theory of value. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1993) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallego G, Moon I (1993) The distribution free newsboy problem: Review and extensions. J Oper Res Soc 44(8):825–834

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garman MB, Ohlson JA (1981) Valuation of risky assets in arbitrage-free economies with transactions costs. J Financ Econ 9(3):271–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griva I, Nash SG, Sofer A (2009) Linear and nonlinear optimization, 2nd edn. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia

  • Hax H (1964) Investitions- und Finanzplanung mit Hilfe der linearen Programmierung. Schmalenbachs Zeitschrift für betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung 16(6):430–446

    Google Scholar 

  • Hering T (2000) Das allgemeine Zustands-Grenzpreismodell zur Bewertung von Unternehmen und anderen unsicheren Zahlungsströmen. Die Betriebswirtschaft 60(3):362–378

    Google Scholar 

  • Hering T, Olbrich M, Steinrücke M (2006) Valuation of start-up internet companies. Int J Technol Manag 33(4):406–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hering T, Toll C (2015) Application of alternative valuation formulas for a company sale. Glob Econ Finance J 8(2):14–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hering T, Toll C, Kirilova PK (2014a) Acquiring a company: Assessing the maximum affordable price. World Rev Bus Res 4(3):35–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Hering T, Toll C, Kirilova PK (2014b) How to compute a decision-oriented business value for a company sale. J Account Finance Econ 4(1):43–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Hering T, Toll C, Kirilova PK (2015a) Business valuation for a company purchase: Application of valuation formulas. Int Rev Bus Res Pap 11(1):1–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Hering T, Toll C, Kirilova PK (2015b) Selling a company: Assessing the minimum demandable price. Glob Rev Account Finance 6(1):19–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hering T, Toll C, Kirilova PK (2016) Assessing the maximum expendable quota for a milestone financing provided by a venture capitalist. Int J Entrep Ventur 8(1):102–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertz DB (1964) Risk analysis in capital investment. Harvard Bus Rev 42(1):95–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Höck M (2005) Dienstleistungsmanagement aus produktionswirtschaftlicher Sicht. Gabler, Wiesbaden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Höck M (2008) Ein Planungsansatz zur Kapazitätsdimensionierung von IuK-Techniken. Zeitschrift für Planung und Unternehmenssteuerung 19(2):143–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurd CC (1954) Simulation by computation as an operations research tool. J Opt Soc Am 2(2):205–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Inwinkl P, Schneider G (2008) Unternehmensbewertung und Zustands-Grenzpreismodelle bei Agency-Problemen. Betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung und Praxis 60(3):276–292

    Google Scholar 

  • Inwinkl P, Kortebusch D, Schneider G (2009) Das allgemeine Zustands-Grenzpreismodell zur Bewertung von Unternehmen bei beidseitigen Agency-Konflikten. Betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung und Praxis 61(4):403–421

    Google Scholar 

  • Khouja M (1999) The single-period (news-vendor) problem: Literature review and suggestions for future research. Omega 27(5):537–553

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koller T, Goedhart MH, Wessels D (2010) Valuation, 5th edn. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Laux H, Franke G (1969) Zum Problem der Bewertung von Unternehmungen und anderen Investitionsgütern. Unternehmensforschung 13(3):205–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerm M, Rollberg R, Kurz P (2012) Financial valuation of start-up businesses with and without venture capital. Int J Entrep Ventur 4(3):257–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lintner J (1965) The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Rev Econ Stat 47(1):13–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luenberger DG (2016) Linear and nonlinear programming, 4th edn. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz HM (1952) Portfolio selection. J Finance 7(1):77–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Matschke MJ (1975) Der Entscheidungswert der Unternehmung. Gabler, Wiesbaden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Matschke MJ, Brösel G (2013) Unternehmensbewertung, Funktionen—Methoden—Grundsätze, 4th edn. Springer, Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  • Matschke MJ, Brösel G, Matschke X (2010) Fundamentals of functional business valuation. J Bus Valuat Econ Loss Anal 5(1):1–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Mossin J (1966) Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34(4):768–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullins DW (1982) Does the capital asset pricing model work? Harvard Bus Rev 60(1):105–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers SC (1974) Interactions of corporate financing and investment decisions—implications for capital budgeting. J Finance 29(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olbrich M, Brösel G, Hasslinger M (2009) The valuation of airport slots. J Air Law Commer 74(4):897–917

    Google Scholar 

  • Olbrich M, Quill T, Rapp DJ (2015) Business valuation inspired by the Austrian school. J Bus Valuat Econ Loss Anal 10(1):1–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pfaff D, Pfeiffer T, Gathge D (2002) Unternehmensbewertung und Zustands-Grenzpreismodelle. Betriebs-wirtschaftliche Forschung und Praxis 54(2):198–210

    Google Scholar 

  • Porteus EL (1990) Stochastic inventory theory. In: Heyman DP, Sobel MJ (eds) Handbooks in operations research and management science, vol 2. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 605–652

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapp DJ (2015) Boom and bust: The role of business valuation in the recent financial crisis. J Prices Mark 4(1):86–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossi R, Prestwich S, Tarim SA, Hnich B (2014) Confidence-based optimisation for the newsvendor problem under binomial, Poisson and exponential demand. Eur J Oper Res 239(3):674–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salazar RC, Sen SK (1968) A simulation model of capital budgeting under uncertainty. Manag Sci 15(4):B161–B179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sankarasubramanian E, Kumaraswamy S (1983) Optimal ordering quantity for pre-determined level of profit. Manag Sci 29(4):512–514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Finance 19(3):425–442

    Google Scholar 

  • Silver EA, Pyke DF, Peterson R (1998) Inventory Management and Production Planning and Scheduling, 3rd edn. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Strang G (1986) Introduction to applied mathematics. Wellelsley-Cambridge Press, Wellesley

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1958) Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. Rev Econ Stud 25(2):65–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toll C (2010) Unternehmensbewertung bei Vorliegen verhandelbarer Zahlungsmodalitäten. Betriebs-wirtschaftliche Forschung und Praxis 62(4):384–411

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingartner HM (1963) Mathematical programming and the analysis of capital budgeting problems. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christian Toll.

Appendices

A Convex optimization in a nutshell

A convex objective function \(F(\mathbf{v})\) of \(n+1\) variables under m convex constraints \(\mathbf{f}(\mathbf{v})\le \mathbf{0}\) can be formulated as a Lagrange function:

$$\begin{aligned} \phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u}) = F(\mathbf{v}) + \mathbf{u}\cdot \mathbf{f}(\mathbf{v}) \qquad \qquad \mathbf{v}\in {\mathbb R}_0^{+ \, n+1}, \mathbf{u}\in {\mathbb R}_0^{+ \, m} \end{aligned}$$
(32)

where \(\mathbf{v}\) and \(\mathbf{u}\) are the corresponding non-negative primal and dual variables, respectively (Bronstein and Semendjajew 1991). For the primal optimization problem this function is minimized with respect to \(\mathbf{v}\) and for the dual optimization problem maximized with respect to \(\mathbf{u}\). The resulting saddle point problem defines the interval for the optimal solution as follows (please observe the fine symmetry also with regard to the Kuhn-Tucker conditions):

$$\begin{aligned} \phi (\bar{\mathbf{v}},\mathbf{u}) = \min \limits _{\mathbf{v}} \phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u}) \le \phi (\bar{\mathbf{v}},\bar{\mathbf{u}}) \le \max \limits _{\mathbf{u}} \phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u}) = \phi (\mathbf{v},\bar{\mathbf{u}}) . \end{aligned}$$
(33)

In the optimum this interval is mapped onto the optimal point

$$\begin{aligned} \phi (\bar{\mathbf{v}},\bar{\mathbf{u}}) = \min \limits _{\mathbf{v}}(\max \limits _{\mathbf{u}} \phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u})) = \max \limits _{\mathbf{u}} (\min \limits _{\mathbf{v}} \phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u})) . \end{aligned}$$
(34)

The sufficient conditions for the existence of a global optimum are called Karush-Kuhn-Tucker or Kuhn-Tucker conditions, see Luenberger (2016) or Strang (1986), p. 724, which can be formulated for the primal problem as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \text{ a) } \mathbf{f}(\bar{\mathbf{v}}) =\bar{\partial }_{\mathbf{u}} \phi (\bar{\mathbf{v}},\mathbf{u}) \le \mathbf{0},\qquad \text{ b) } \bar{\mathbf{u}} \cdot \bar{\partial }_{\mathbf{u}} \phi (\bar{\mathbf{v}},\mathbf{u}) = 0,\qquad \text{ c) } \mathbf{u}\ge \mathbf{0} \end{aligned}$$
(35)

with a function \(\mathbf{f}(\mathbf{v})\) convex in \(\mathbf{v}\). Here, \(\partial _{\mathbf{v}} \phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u})\) denotes the gradient of \(\phi \) with respect to \(\mathbf{v}\) with the notation \((\frac{\partial \phi }{\partial v_1},\ldots ,\frac{\partial \phi }{\partial v_{n+1}})\). \(\bar{\partial }_{\mathbf{v}}(\cdot )\) means \(\partial _{\mathbf{v}} (\cdot ) \Big |_{\mathbf{v}= \bar{\mathbf{v}}}\).

The Kuhn-Tucker conditions for the dual optimization problem read as

$$\begin{aligned} \text{ a) } \bar{\partial }_{\mathbf{v}} \phi (\mathbf{v},\bar{\mathbf{u}}) \ge \mathbf{0}\qquad \text{ b) } \bar{\mathbf{v}} \cdot \bar{\partial }_{\mathbf{v}} \phi (\mathbf{v},\bar{\mathbf{u}}) = 0,\qquad \text{ c) } \mathbf{v}\ge \mathbf{0} . \end{aligned}$$
(36)

If we consider a linear equation system like in the linear programming case, the given primal optimization problem is simply rearranged to obtain its corresponding dual optimization problem and vice versa. Let \(\max _{\mathbf{v}} \mathbf{c}\cdot \mathbf{v}\) be the linear objective function under the linear constraints \({\mathbb H} \cdot \mathbf{v}\le \mathbf{b}\) such that the Lagrange function can be formulated as \(\phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u}) = -\mathbf{c}\cdot \mathbf{v}+ \mathbf{u}\cdot ({\mathbb H} \cdot \mathbf{v}- \mathbf{b})\). Rearranging terms we obtain the expression \(\phi (\mathbf{v},\mathbf{u}) = -\mathbf{b}\cdot \mathbf{u}+ \mathbf{v}\cdot (-\mathbf{c}+ {\mathbb H}{}^T \cdot \mathbf{u})\). Hence, by considering the Kuhn-Tucker conditions of the dual optimization problem the Lagrange function \(\min _{\mathbf{u}} \mathbf{b}\cdot \mathbf{u}\) must hold under the linear constraints \({\mathbb H}{}^T \cdot \mathbf{u}\ge \mathbf{c}\).

B The newsvendor model revisited

We are able to transform the profit function \(P(Q) = E(Q)-L(Q)\) by using E(Q) from Eq. (18) and L(Q) from Eq. (19) as

$$\begin{aligned} P(Q)= & {} - c \, Q + \int ^Q_0 (p_{NV} \, x - c_H \, (Q-x)) \, d\psi (x) + \int ^\infty _Q (p_{NV} \, Q - c_S \, (x-Q)) \, d\psi (x)\nonumber \\= & {} - c \, Q + p_{NV} \, \mu - c_H \, (Q-\mu ) + (p_{NV} + c_S + c_H)\, \int ^\infty _Q (Q-x)\, d\psi (x) \end{aligned}$$
(37)

under the presumption that \(\psi (x)|_{-\infty }^0 \approx 0\). For the maximum at \(Q^*\)

$$\begin{aligned} P'(Q) \Big |_{Q = Q^*} = -c - c_H + (p_{NV} + c_S + c_H) \, \int ^\infty _{Q^*} d\psi (x) = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(38)

holds such that by using \(\Psi (Q) = \psi (x) \Big |^Q_{-\infty } = (1 - \psi (x)\Big |^\infty _Q)\) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \Psi (Q^*) = \psi (x \le Q^*) = \frac{p_{NV} + c_S - c}{p_{NV} + c_S + c_H} \end{aligned}$$
(39)

as a critical fractile of the distribution function \(\psi (Q)\), see Sankarasubramanian and Kumaraswamy (1983) or Silver et al. (1998), pp. 385–389. Due to

$$\begin{aligned} P''(Q) = (p_{NV} + c_S + c_H) (-\Psi '(Q)) \le 0 \end{aligned}$$
(40)

and \(\Psi '(Q) \ge 0\) we can conclude that P(Q) is concave with respect to Q. We see that the inequality \(c \ge -c_H\) must be satisfied since \(\Psi (Q) \le 1\) in Eq. (39). Moreover, \(k \le K\) holds by definition, see Eq. (20). If we examine the dual Kuhn-Tucker condition of the multi-period newsvendor model in Eq. (26) for \(\bar{Q}_t > 0\) in combination with the nonlinear cost term \(h_c \, Q_t^\beta \) we get for \(\bar{Q}_t < Q_t^*\)

$$\begin{aligned} d_{t+1} \, (c + c_H - (p_{NV} + c_S + c_H)\, (1-\Psi (\bar{Q_t})) + \beta \, h_c \, \bar{Q}_t^{\beta -1} - c_{ct+1}) + d_{t} \, c_{ct} = 0 . \end{aligned}$$
(41)

Recalling \(\frac{d_{t+1}}{d_t} = q^{-1}\) we can find a lower bound by assuming \((1 - \Psi (\bar{Q_t})) = 1\) as well as \(\beta = 1\) for \(\bar{Q}_t > \text{ exp }\left( {\frac{\text{ ln }(\beta )}{(1-\beta )}}\right) \) and can derive the following inequalities which have to be satisfied by the parameters:

$$\begin{aligned}&q \, k \le K : p_{NV} + c_S \ge c + h_c - K + q \, k \nonumber \\&q \, k > K : p_{NV} + c_S \ge c + h_c - k + q \, K . \end{aligned}$$
(42)

C Are utility functions derivable under practical circumstances?

The empirical derivation of consistent utility functions, which are stable over time, causes insurmountable difficulties for every-day business practice. The well-known paradox of Allais (1953) proves that even under a seemingly plausible preference order a utility function may not exist. Furthermore, because of the axiom of continuity of utility functions according to the well-established principles of Bernoulli it may be impossible to reject alternatives which may be life-threatening for a company, especially when associated only with a small probability. Consumption utility functions are for real decision models no practicable concept and are even more difficult to derive if we consider a multitude of owners. A target which either strives for maximizing end value or consumption spending, fixing one variable by maximizing the other, meets the requirement of operationality and flexibility and serves the interests of owners in view of their demand for additional wealth or income. It is furthermore consistent with empirically observable behavior of German corporate companies which preferably pay a fixed dividend and plow the rest back under the maxim of maximizing end value or stock price.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Toll, C., Kintzel, O. A nonlinear state marginal price vector model for the task of business valuation. A case study: The dimensioning of IT-service companies under nonlinear synergy effects. Cent Eur J Oper Res 27, 1079–1105 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10100-018-0535-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10100-018-0535-x

Keywords

Navigation