Skip to main content

Electronic Negotiation and Behavioral Elements

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Group Decision and Negotiation
  • 102 Accesses

Abstract

Systems based on information and communication technologies have facilitated the support or automation (partial/complete) of many a task and process, including negotiation. Electronic Negotiation Systems (ENSs), whose genesis and evolution can be traced to software systems of the 1970s, have grown significantly since the advent of the Internet, in terms of both scope and numbers. Yet, given the complexity of negotiation, there is a need for incorporating behavioral elements into ENSs. This chapter, which concerns a two-party negotiation setting, outlines the behavioral negotiation literature and describes the evolution of ENSs, thus contextualizing the problem of incorporating behavior into negotiation systems. We propose a framework to approach this problem, entailing a characterization of user-preferences, and in turn, the resulting negotiation strategy. We use relevant exemplars from the literature to illustrate how the trade-off between the fidelity and tractability of such characterizations can determine the level of automation afforded by an ENS. Research opportunities arising from endowing ENSs with behavioral features are identified.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    An ENS (Kersten and Lai 2007) is “a software that employs internet technologies and it is deployed on the web for the purpose of facilitating, organizing, supporting and/or automating activities undertaken by the negotiators and/or third party”.

  2. 2.

    In the sense of Kersten and Lo (2003), ENSs concern both science and engineering aspects. Our survey considers the science aspect [Stroebel and Weinhardt (2003): gives software-engineering ENS taxonomies].

  3. 3.

    While the description herein is for offers over the negotiation rounds, it can also be readily extended for utility values across rounds (and in turn utility concessions). The latter form, wherein P’s in (1)–(2) are replaced by utility values, is used in Appendix C.

References

  • Antoniou G, Harmelan F (2003) Handbook of ontologies. Springer

    Google Scholar 

  • Arunachalam V, Lytle A, Wall J (2001) An evaluation of two mediationtechniques, negotiator power, and culture in negotiation. J Appl Soc Psychol 31(5):951–980

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attema A, Brouwer W (2013) In search of a preferred preference elicitation method: a test of the internal consistency of choice and matching tasks. J Econ Psychol 39:126–140

    Google Scholar 

  • Attema AE, Bleichrodt H, Rohde KIM, Wakker PP (2010) Time-tradeoff sequences for analyzing discounting and time inconsistency. Manag Sci 56(11):2015–2030

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1984) The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Benton AA, Druckman D (1973) Salient solutions and the bargaining behavior of representatives and nonrepresentatives. Int J Group Tensions 3:28–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Bleichrodt H, Rohde KI, Wakker PP (2009) Non-hyperbolic time inconsistency. Games Econ Behav 66(1):27–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carnevale PJ, Lawler EJ (1986) Time pressure and the development of integrative agreements in bilateral negotiation. J Confl Resolut 30:636–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan DK-S, Triandis H, Carnevale PJ, Tam A (1992) A cross-cultural comparison of negotiation: effects of collectivism, relationship between negotiators, and concession pattern on negotiation. Working paper University of Illinois

    Google Scholar 

  • De Dreu CK, Beersma B, Steinel W, Van Kleef GA (2007) The psychology of negotiation: principles and basic processes. In: Kruglanski AW, Higgins ET (eds) Social psychology: Handbook of basic principles, 2nd edn. Guilford, pp 608–629

    Google Scholar 

  • Druckman D (1986). “Stages, turning points, and crises: Negotiating military base rights, Spain and the United States,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 30, 327–360

    Google Scholar 

  • Druckman D, Ramberg B, Harris R (2002) Computer-assisted international negotiation: a tool for research and practice. Group Decis Negot 11(3):231–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekman P, Friesen WV, Ellsworth P (1971) Emotion in the human face: guide-lines for research and an integration of findings: guidelines for research and an integration of findings. Pergamon, Elmsford

    Google Scholar 

  • Etezadi-Amoli J (2010) The adoption and use of negotiation systems. In: Handbook of group decision and negotiation. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 393–408

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Faratin P, Sierra C, Jennings NR (1998) Negotiation decision functions for autonomous agents. Int J Robot Auton Syst 24(3–4):159–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filzmoser (2010) Springer book. Simulation of Automated Negotiation, 2010 Springer-Verlag/Wien ISBN 978-3-7091-0132-2

    Google Scholar 

  • Fredrick S, Loewenstein G, O’Donoghue T (2002) Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. J Econ Lit 40(2):351–401

    Google Scholar 

  • Giebels E, Dreu CD, de Vliert EV (2000) Interdependence in negotiation: effects of exit options and social motive on distributive and integrative negotiation. Eur J Soc Psychol 30:255–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harnick F, De Dreu CKW (2004) Negotiating values or resources: the moderating impact of time pressure. Eur J Soc Psychol 34:595–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings J, Ceusters W, Mulligan K, Smith B (2012) Annotating affective neuroscience data with the emotion ontology. In: Towards an ontology of mental functioning, workshop at international conference on biomedical ontology, Graz, 22 July 2012

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatta T, Ohbuchi KI, Fukuno M (2007) An experimental study on the effects of exitability and correctability on electronic negotiation. Negot J 23(3):283–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang J, Fox MS (2006) An ontology of trust: formal semantics and transitivity. In: Proceedings of the 8th international conference on electronic commerce: the new e-commerce: innovations for conquering current barriers, obstacles and limitations to conducting successful business on the internet. ACM, New York, pp 259–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson NA, Cooper RB, Chin WW (2009) Anger and flaming in computer-mediated negotiation among strangers. Decis Support Syst 46(3):660–672

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelly S (2014) Towards a negative ontology of leadership. Hum Relat 67(8):905–922

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kersten GE, Lai H (2007) Negotiation support and e-negotiation systems: an overview. Group Decis Negot 16(6):553–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kersten and Lai (2010) Electronic Negotiation: Foundations, Systems and Processes in Kilgour, C. Eden (eds.), Handbook of Group Decision and Negotiation, Advances in Group Decision and Negotiation 4, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-90-481-9097-3_22

  • Kersten GE, Lo G (2003) Aspire: an integrated negotiation support system and software agents for e-business negotiation. Int J Internet Enterp Manag 1(3):293–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kersten GE, Noronha SJ (1999) WWW-based negotiation support: design, implementation, and use. Decis Support Syst 25:135–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilgour and Eden (2010) Handbook of Group Decision and Negotiation. In Kilgour, D. Marc, Eden, Colin (Eds.), Springer. ISBN 978-90-481-9097-3

    Google Scholar 

  • Kramer and Messick (1995) Negotiation as a Social Process. Roderick M. Kramer and David M. Messick, eds. Newbury Park, CA: Sage

    Google Scholar 

  • Krishnaswamy V, Pahuja A, Sundarraj RP (2016) Integrating time-preferences into E-negotiation systems: a model, elicitation approach and experimental implications. Group Decis Negot 25(6):1137–1167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai-Huat Lim and Izak Benbasat (1992) A Theoretical Perspective of Negotiation Support Systems, Journal of Management Information Systems, 9(3):27–44, https://doi.org/10.1080/07421222.1992.11517966

  • Lau RK (2009) An evolutionary approach for intelligent negotiation agents in e-marketplaces. In: Nguyen N, Jain L (eds) Intelligent agents in the evolution of web and applications. Springer, Berlin/Heidelberg, pp 279–301

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Lin R, Liang C, Duan R, Chen Y, Tao C (2018) Visualized emotion ontology: a model for representing visual cues of emotions. BMC Med Inform Decis Mak 1818(Suppl 2):64 https://doi.org/10.1186/s12911-018-0634-6

  • Loewenstein G, Prelec D (1992) Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. Q J Econ 107(2):573–597

    Google Scholar 

  • Malhotra D, Bazerman MH (2008) Psychological influence in negotiation: an introduction long overdue. J Manag 34(3):509–531

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinovsky B (2015) Emotion in group decision and negotiation, vol 7. In: Advances in Group Decision and Negotiation, Martinovsky B (ed). Springer Netherlands. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-9963-8_2

  • McAlister L, Bazerman MH, Fader P (1986) Power and goal setting in-channel negotiations. J Mark Res 23:228–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mok WWH, Sundarraj RP (2005) Learning algorithms for single-instance electronic negotiations using the time-dependent Behavioral tactic. ACM Trans Internet Technol 5(1):195–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee A, Sundarraj RP, Dutta K (2016) On considering customer’s short-term preferences for resource allocation in cloud computing spot markets. In: Workshop on information technology and systems (WITS 2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Nash JF (1950) Equilibrium points in n-person games. Proc Natl Acad Sci 36(1):48–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olekalns M, Druckman D (2015) With feeling: how emotions shape negotiation. In: Martinovsky B (ed) Emotion in group decision and negotiation, Springer Netherlands (pp 33–50). Springer, Netherlands. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-9963-8

  • Petty RE, Cacioppo JT (1981) Attitudes and persuation: classic and contemporary approaches. William C. Brown, Dubuque

    Google Scholar 

  • Plutchik, R. (1980). A general psychoevolutionary theory of emotion. In R. Plutchik & H. Kellerman (Eds.), Emotion: Theory, research and experience, Theories of emotion (Vol. 1, pp. 3–33). New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pruitt D, Carnevale P (2011) Negotiation and social conflict. Open University Press, Maiden Head, Berkshire, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roszkowska E, Wachowicz T (2015) Inaccuracy in defining preferences by the electronic negotiation system users. In: Kamiński B, Kersten GE, Szapiro T (eds) Outlooks and insights on group decision and negotiation. Springer International Publishing, Cham, pp 131–143

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Salo A, Hamalainen R (2020) MCDA methods for group decision processes: an overview. In: Eden C, Kilgour M (eds) Handbook of group decision and negotiation. Springer, Cham. (Other Chapters)

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1937) A Note on Measurement of Utility. Review of. EconomicStudies, 4(2):155–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Schoop M (2010) Support of complex electronic negotiations. In: Handbook of group decision and negotiation. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 409–423

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schoop M, Jertila A, List T (2003) Negoisst: a negotiation support system for electronic business-to-business negotiations in e-commerce. Data Knowl Eng 47(3):371–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sormaz D, Sarkar A (2019) SIMPM – upper-level ontology for manufacturing process plan network generation. Robot Comput Integr Manuf 55:183–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stroebel M, Weinhardt C (2003) The Montreal taxonomy for electronic negotiations. Group Decis Negot 12:143–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sundarraj R, Mok W (2011) Models for human negotiation elements: validation, and implications for electronic procurement. IEEE Trans Eng Manag 58(3):412–430

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundarraj and Mok (2012) Optimization-Based Methods for Improving the Accuracy and Outcome of Learning in Electronic Procurement Negotiations IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 59(4):666–678

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundarraj RP, Shi X (2012) Optimization-based methods for improving the accuracy and outcome of learning in electronic procurement negotiations. IEEE Trans Eng Manag 99:1–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Sykora MD, Jackson T, O’Brien A, Elayan S (2013) Emotive ontology: extracting fine-grained emotions from terse, informal messages. IADIS Int J Comput Sci Inf Syst 8(2):1 06–11 8. ISSN: 1646–3692

    Google Scholar 

  • Tamma V, Phelpsa S, Dickinson I, Wooldridge M (2005) Ontologies for supporting negotiation in e-commerce. Eng Appl Artif Intell 18:223–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trope Y, Liberman N (2003) Temporal construal theory of time-dependent preferences. Psychol Econ Decis 1:235–249

    Google Scholar 

  • Van de Vliert E (1990) Positive effects of conflict: a field assessment. Int J Confl Manag I:69–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Kleef GA (2009) How emotions regulate social life: the emotions as social information (EASI) model. Curr Dir Psychol Sci 18(3):184–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Poucke D, Bulens M (2002) Predicting the outcome of a two-partyprice negotiation: contributions of reservation price, aspiration priceand opening offer. J Econ Psychol 23:67–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venkatesh V, Morris MG, Davis GB, Davis FD (2003) User acceptance of information technology: toward a unified view. MIS Q 27:425–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vetschera R, Koeszegi ST, Schoop M (2013) Electronic negotiation systems. In: Wiley encyclopedia of operations research and management science, pp 1–8

    Google Scholar 

  • Vetschera R, Filzmoser M, Miterhofer R (2014) An analytical approach to offer generation in concession-based negotiation processes. Group Decis Negot 23:71–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walton RE, McKersie R (1965) A behavioral theory of labor negotiations: an analysis of a social interaction system. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Watrobski J, Jankowski J, Ziemba P, Karczmarczyk A (2019) Generalised framework for multi-criteria method selection. Omega 86:107–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to R. P. Sundarraj .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix A: Negotiation Strategy

Researchers on electronic negotiations (Step 1 of section “Integration Exemplars”) have identified a number of strategies that govern the offers made in a negotiation, including for example, time-dependent, resource-dependent, and tit-for-tat. Faratin et al. (1998) gives function forms of these strategies that provide the offer that must be made in a given round.

Drawing upon previous research (e.g., Faratin et al. 1998; Mok and Sundarraj 2005; Sundarraj and Mok 2012), we illustrate below the time-dependent strategy. Here, the offersFootnote 3 are generated by considering the following parameters: the starting offer; the reservation offer; the maximum time allowed for the negotiation; and the rate at which concessions are made as the negotiator proceeds from the starting offer to the reservation offer. Based on these parameters, a mathematical of the offer at time t is given by:

$$ P(t)={P}_{\mathrm{min}}+{e}^{{\left(1-\frac{t}{T_{\mathrm{max}}}\right)}^{\beta}\ln (K)}\left({P}_{\mathrm{max}}-{P}_{\mathrm{min}}\right)\quad\mathrm{if}\ \mathrm{utility}\ \mathrm{is}\ \mathrm{decreasing} $$
(1)
$$ P(t)={P}_{\mathrm{min}}+\left(1-{e}^{{\left(1-\frac{t}{T_{\mathrm{max}}}\right)}^{\beta}\ln (K)}\right)\left({P}_{\mathrm{max}}-{P}_{\mathrm{min}}\right)\quad\mathrm{if}\ \mathrm{utility}\ \mathrm{is}\ \mathrm{increasing}, $$
(2)

where

t

Is time (number of turns) in the interval [0,Tmax]

Pt

Is the value of the negotiating issue proposed at time t

Pmin

Is the minimum value of the negotiation issue

Pmax

Is the maximum value of the negotiation issue

K

Is a constant that determines the value of the first offer negotiating issue in the first offer

Tmax

Is the time limit (maximum number of turns) proposed by an agent

β

Is a constant (concession rate) determining the degree of convexity

The five parameters, Pmin, Pmax, Tmax, β, and k, uniquely determine the function’s range and can yield a rich set of offers. For example, even if Pmin, Pmax, Tmax and k are kept constant, a change in β can yield significant changes in the offer prices. This is illustrated in Fig. 4, wherein the offer-differential for the first five turns is less than 20 for β = 0.1 and more than 200 for β = 7.5. Such offer-differentials significantly impact the negotiation process and outcome.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Illustrating an offer-generation strategy

The above characterization is in terms of single negotiation-issue (e.g., price), although it can be applied to multi-issue negotiations as well (involving other factors such as lead time etc.). With multiple issues, under the important condition that the negotiation issues are separable, different decision-functions can be used to the different issues, with the various negotiation parameter-values applicable to one issue being different from those for another (e.g., maximum/minimum values applicable to lead time are likely to be different from those for price).

Appendix B: Eliciting Time Preferences

Preferences have to be elicited both for the type of negotiation strategy that the user wants to employ, as well as aspects pertaining to the behavioral element. Here, we will focus on the latter for the case of time-preference (Step 2 of section “Integration Exemplars”); more details are available in Krishnaswamy et al. (2016).

The varying impatience levels described in section “Integration 2” indicate that preferential independence does not hold in the case of time-preference models. In both increasing and decreasing impatience types, changing the value of time can result in a change in price. That is the delivery time has an effect on price. In order to incorporate this (instead of a linear additive utility model), the utility U(p, d) of a price-delivery-time combination (p, d) is given by (Loewenstein and Prelec 1992; Bleichrodt et al. 2009):

$$ U\left(p,d\right)=\left(\frac{p^{max}-p\ }{p^{max}-{p}^{min}}\right)\ \phi (d), $$
(3)

where ϕ(d) is the discounting function.

A number of normative models have been proposed to capture the functional form of ϕ(d). Samuelson (1937) assumed that several factors that devalue utility with respect to time may be amalgamated, and proposed the exponential discounting model (4). Exponential discounting model has capabilities to represent only stationary time preference (i.e., constant impatience), where the ratio ϕ(d)/ϕ(d + 1) is constant with time. Stationary Time Preference (Constant Impatience):

$$ \phi (d)={e}^{- rd},r>0 $$
(4)

where r is the rate of discounting.

Experiments have, however, shown that impatience behaviors have anomalies and can be decreasing or increasing with time (Loewenstein and Prelec 1992; Attema et al. 2010). Loewenstein and Prelec (1992) proposed the generalized hyperbolic function to model some of the anomalies.

$$ \phi (d)={\left(1+\alpha d\right)}^{-\beta /\alpha },\alpha, \beta >0 $$
(5)

where α, β are constants.

The above hyperbolic discounting function is not robust to model increasing impatience of any degree (Bleichrodt et al. 2009). Bleichrodt et al. (2009) proposed a function shown in (6) that can model both increasing (δ < 0) and decreasing impatience (0 < δ < 1):

$$ \phi (d)={ke}^{-{rd}^{1-\delta }},\, r>0,\, \delta <1,\, k>0 $$
(6)

where r, δ, k are constants. While (6) can be more robust, irrespective of the functional form, ϕ(d) has to be obtained. The broad steps entailed in this are as follows:

  • Step B1: Elicitation of user preferences by administering a time-preference elicitation (TPE) task

  • Step B2: Calculation of indifference points from the user choices

  • Step B3: Calculation of discount factors and plotting of discounting curve

  • Step B4: Parameter estimation using curve fitting function and calculation of discount function φ(d)

The TPE task presents the user with a set of questions between a “larger-sooner cost” and a “smaller-later cost” (note: the same can be readily adapted to rewards as well). The user answers the questions based on the outcomes and time delay. The questions are presented in a way that the user exhibits indifference between the available choices at a point of the task, known as the indifference point. The indifference points are normalized to get the utility points from which, for example, curve fitting can be used to obtain the parameters of the discount function. There are two approaches to Steps B1 and B2 above: choice and matching-based (Attema and Brouwer 2013) methods.

A simple choice method is titration-based choice. Here, the participants make a choice between two options: delayed smaller price and immediate larger price. Such option questions are then systematically posed for a range of amount-delay combinations. In a simple version of the procedure, for example, for a given delay, a series of option-questions are posed by varying (i.e., titrating) the amounts, and then the indifference point is noted for this delay. This step is then repeated for various delay-values.

Example 1: Choice Based Method

Consider a user who has to choose between delivery tomorrow for $100 or a free delivery in 3 days. If the user chooses free delivery in 3 days, then the paid delivery price is decreased by some percentage, say, to $88, and a similar question is posed. If the user now chooses delivery tomorrow for $88, then indifference point is $94 (average of 88 and 100). On the other hand, if, in response to the original question, the user chooses delivery tomorrow for $100, then the paid delivery price is increased by some percentage, say, to $108, and then similar questions are posed until the indifference point is obtained. Then, the whole procedure is repeated for a different delay.

The titration choice method tends to cover a range of amount-delay combinations and that can tend to reduce decision-biases on the part of the participant. It is, however, time consuming, so there are other methods, including other choice-based methods and the matching approaches given next.

Matching task involves matching pairs of alternatives to indifference. Of the various types of matching methods, time-trade-off (TTO) method is an example (Attema et al. 2010). In the matching methods, the user has to fill in one of the attributes of one pair which makes it indifferent to other pair. This procedure gives information on the discount function without requiring assumptions about the shape of the discount function or the validity of the DU model. The TTO method entails a sequence t0, t1…, tn of time points such that there exist two outcomes β and γ with (t0: β) ∼ (t1: γ) (∼ is symbol for indifference), (t1: β) ∼ (t2: γ), …….(tn-1: β) ∼ (tn: γ); that is, each delay between two consecutive time points exactly offsets the same outcome improvement, and therefore makes both tuples indifferent.

Example 2: Matching Task Time-Trade-off Method

Figure 5 illustrates this approach. As given in the top box, the user is asked how many days he/she is willing to wait for a lower delivery price of $50. Assume that the response is 3 days. This implies that, the user is indifferent between paying delivery price of INR 150 on day 0 to paying delivery price of INR 50 on day 3. This response is chained in the next question (box 2), and the procedure continues.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Example for TTO task

Appendix C: Integration of Time Preference

Once the time-preference is characterized, it can be used to alter (Step 3 of section “Integration Exemplars”) the negotiation strategy (see also Krishnaswamy et al. 2016). Step (a) uses a strategy to determine the concession that must be offered, giving bounds on the utility value that must be respected during offer generation (note: besides concessions, section 2 lists other negotiation principles as well). Step (b) gives the mechanism for generating multiple trade-off offers.

  1. a)

    The buyer fixes the utility Ut(p, d)for the current round t (t ∈{1, 2, …Tmax}) based on the concession level ut. Ut(p, d) is given by:

$$ {U}_t\left(p,d\right)={U}_{t-1}\left(p,d\right)-{u}_t $$
(7)

where the initial U0 = 1.0 and ut is determined by using a concession tactic (Appendix A gives more details of one concession tactic to obtain round-utility).

  1. b)

    The ENS can then create an offer-tuple by choosing p-d values to satisfy (8) (round index t is dropped below):

$$ U\left(p,d\right)=\left(\frac{p^{max}-\, p\ }{p^{max}-{p}^{min}}\right)\phi (d) $$
(8)

That is, by choosing price from [pmin, pmax], we can determine the delivery time with (9); alternatively, for delivery time in [dmin, dmax] the price can be computed using (10):

$$ p=\left[{p}^{max}-\frac{U\left(p,d\right)\ \left[{p}^{max}-{p}^{min}\right]}{\phi (d)}\right], $$
(9)
$$ d=-\left(\frac{1}{r}\right)\mathit{\ln}{\left(\left[\frac{U\left(p,d\right)\ \left[{p}^{max}-{p}^{min}\right]}{\left({p}^{max}-p\right)k}\right]\right)}^{\frac{1}{1-\delta }} $$
(10)

where ϕ(d) is a suitably chosen discounting function. This way the ENS can exploit price-time trade-offs and propose multiple offers, thereby reducing impasse and improving the possibility of integrative offers. If the seller accepts the offer or the negotiation deadline is reached, go to step (d).

  1. c)

    The seller proposes a set of counter-offer(s). If the buyer accepts the offer or the negotiation deadline is reached, go to step (d); else go to Step (a).

  2. d)

    Stop.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Sundarraj, R.P. (2020). Electronic Negotiation and Behavioral Elements. In: Kilgour, D., Eden, C. (eds) Handbook of Group Decision and Negotiation. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-12051-1_39-1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-12051-1_39-1

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-12051-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-12051-1

  • eBook Packages: Springer Reference Behavioral Science and PsychologyReference Module Humanities and Social SciencesReference Module Business, Economics and Social Sciences

Publish with us

Policies and ethics